Saturday, November 6, 2010

Downloading Lifelong Course Files

1, Select the following link and right click.
2. Select the Go to option and left click.
https://docs.google.com/?hl=en&tab=wo&authuser=0#all

This will take you to the window in the Google Documents where the lifelong files are stored.
3. Clock the boxes to the left of the lifelong files you wish to download.
(Note: One file has one slide per page and 102 pages.
The second file has 4 slides per page and 26 pages.)
4. Then under ALL ITEMS Select the drop-down
menu labeled "More Actions."
This will display the drop-down list. Select the last item, Export."
5. Then click the download button.

Finding the Lifelong Folder and Downloadable Docs

1, Select the following link and right click.
2. Select the Go to option and left click.

https://docs.google.com/?hl=en&tab=wo&authuser=0#all

Thursday, February 25, 2010

Why Banks are Reluctant to Reduce the Mortgage Principal?
Banks have been very reluctant to offer mortgage modifications that reduce the principal balance of mortgages. We use an example to explain the banks’ reasoning. We assume banks maximize the expected value cash flows they receive.
Suppose a home was last sold for $400,000 with a $300,000 mortgage. It is now worth $200,000 and it would cost the owner of the mortgage an additional $75,000 to foreclose. If the mortgage balance were reduced to $150,000, there is no chance of default. In that case, the current owner would sell the house rather than default if he could not continue to make the mortgage payments.
Since the home was last sold for $400,000 and is now worth only $200,000, there is $200,000 loss that cannot be avoided. It will be divided between the bank and the homeowner. In addition, there may be another $75,000 of expenses that will be incurred if the final solution involves a default.
The bank’s alternatives are to maintain the loan balance or offer a loan modification. If it modifies the loan bank will receive $150,000. If the bank does not modify the loan, and the homeowner defaults, the bank receives a $200,000 house and incurs $75,000 of expenses to dispose to the house, so its net proceeds are $125,000. If the bank does not modify the loan and the homeowner does not default, the bank receives $300,000.
If the bank believed that the homeowner would certainly to default in case the loan was not modified, it would modify the loan. But if the bank believed that there was even a small probability (14.7% or more) the homeowner would pay the $300,000 mortgage, then will minimize its expected loss by not modifying the loan.
This example illustrates that a major obstacle to loan modification in the current situation is that homeowners are too willing to repay mortgages even when their home is under water. This discourages banks from modifying loans. If homeowners were as opportunistic as banks and were willing to walk away from loans whenever it was in their best interest to do so, without regard to moral qualms, then more loans would be modified and there might be fewer defaults overall.

Wednesday, February 24, 2010

Negative Equity Mortgages:

At the end of 2009, 11.3 million residences were worth less their mortgage balances. In 5 million of these, the value of the property was less than 75% of the mortgage balance.

If a home is worth substantially less than its mortgage, public policy should be aimed at reducing the mortgage balance so that something like the original loan to value ratio is restored. I explain below why this is sensible.

If it is impossible to reduce the mortgage value, many of these deep under water households will opt for a strategic default. In a strategic default, property owners who can afford to continue their mortgage payments stop making payments because it is contrary to their economic interest. Many families avoid choosing the strategic default option because of the mistaken belief that it is immoral. Strategic default is the right thing to do for families who do not have strong non-economic reasons for staying in their under-water home.

Mortgage modifications are not going to happen on any large scale unless there is massive political pressure. Even if mortgage holders were willing to modify mortgages, handling each one on an individual basis is administratively impossible. I will discuss how to automate mortgage modifications in a future blog.

The underwater home problem gets much less attention than it deserves because the households affected are not organized. Strategic defaults that take place one at a time get very little attention.

Suppose the affected homeowners were organized. Then, instead of individual households quietly defaulting with no publicity, batches of thousands might announce that they planned to opt for a strategic default on a given future date if a sensible loan modification program was not available by that date. Each such announcement would constitute front page news and would command considerable attention. There is a terrific opportunity for some grass roots organization here. Move-on.org seems to be asleep at the switch. The mortgage situation is not even among its top ten priorities. Move-on.org, we need you!

If there is no practical program available to eliminate negative equity by reducing the loan balance, then strategic default may be preferable to continuing to pay on an underwater mortgage. There are five main reasons.

· It is the right thing to do.

· It will reduce the moral hazard that now encourages banks to make bad mortgages.

· It will give the Obama administration a second chance to heal the banking system by eliminating some large zombie banks and resurrecting them as real banks.

· It will reduce the dead weight losses associated with foreclosure.

· It will reduce the property deterioration that is likely to occur over time when the homeowner has no equity in his home.

It is the right thing to do.

Millions of homeowners made bad decisions by paying too much for residential property during the housing boom. They are paying dearly for their mistakes, and nothing I am proposing amounts to a bailout for them. But the banks and other financial institutions that originated these mortgages or that purchased the securities based on them also made the same mistake. Real estate finance professionals should have been in a better position than Joe Homeowner to recognize that a housing bubble was inflating.

It will reduce moral hazard.

The banks claim reducing mortgage balances will provides a reward for homeowners who purchased more house than they could afford. Therefore principal reductions create moral hazard and are bad. That argument is a two-edged sword. If banks accepted a home as collateral for too large a mortgage, then forcing homeowners to repay the entire mortgage encourages banks to make lend more than is prudent.

It will turn zombie banks into real banks.

In the first half of 2009 the Obama administration faced the problem of what to do with banks that were effectively insolvent because they had too large a proportion of toxic assets on the balance sheets. A number of prominent economists, including Paul Krugman, Joseph Stiglitz, Simon Johnson, Nouriel Roubini and others, suggested nationalizing the weak banks, stripping out their toxic assets in a government owned bad bank and then selling a cleaned up bank back to the market. Geithner, Summers, et al opted to continue the Bush-Paulsen policy of bailing out the weak banks with taxpayer money. These banks have pretty fallen into the Zombie bank role as was predicted. So with the economy awash with liquidity and banks able to borrow at near zero interest rates, ordinary business still find that credit is extremely tight. If there was a massive reduction of the principal balances of mortgages to reduce the underwater home problem, then some of these banks would found to be insolvent again. And the government would have a second chance to reorganize them the right way and create real bank out of zombie banks.

It will eliminate the dead weight losses due to foreclosure.

Foreclosing on a residential property has been estimated to cost the foreclosing bank $75 to $100 thousand. These costs include such things as legal, appraisal, and brokerage fees, maintenance and repairs on the foreclosed property, security expenses, insurance etc. It does not include the decline in the value of neighborhood property that occurs when a house is foreclosed. Foreclosures rarely occur on homes that have reasonable amounts of positive equity. In that case, homeowners who can’t afford to keep up with the mortgage payments are likely to sell rather than default. For every million foreclosure avoided, society saves $75 to $100 billion.

It will reduce the property deterioration.

The occupant of a home under water is more like a tenant with a bad landlord, than like a homeowner. He will make only those improvements that can be justified by the services they provide him during the time he expects to remain.

Who is Fin-Prof

Who am I?

I am an economist at an Ivy League school, with a background in finance. I am writing a book on what I hope will be the Great Recession; but I am worried that by the time it is ready for publication we will be calling it Great Depression II. In this blog I hope to address policy issues that can’t wait for the glacial pace at which books are turned out